« Taking a break | Main | UK credit survey signals stronger housing demand »

Global economic recovery on track but monetary tightening approaching

Posted on Thursday, April 1, 2010 at 12:19PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

Global industrial output – as proxied by production in the Group of Seven (G7) major economies and seven large emerging economies (the "E7") – fell by 14% between February 2008 and February 2009. This was the largest peacetime decline since the 1930s, though comparable with a 12% fall in G7 output between May 1974 and May 1975, following the first oil shock. (G7 production is a reasonable measure of global output in the 1970s, when today's emerging economies were much less influential.)
 
At the output trough early last year most economic forecasters – including the IMF and OECD – expected any revival in activity to be delayed and weak. As discussed in a post last May, however, this was at odds with the "Zarnowitz rule" that "deep recessions are almost always followed by steep recoveries". Faster money supply growth, moreover, supported a more optimistic prognosis. A year on, a "V"-shaped recovery has been confirmed: G7 plus E7 output had risen by 11% from its February 2009 low by January 2010, to stand only 4% below the February 2008 peak. The recovery has been led by the E7, where output is 9% above its pre-recession peak and rising capacity strains signal a need for significant monetary policy tightening.
 
The 2008-09 output fall, as noted, resembled the 1974-75 contraction. The subsequent recoveries also look similar: G7 production had risen by 9% at the equivalent stage of the post-1975 upswing – see the first chart below. Both recessions were associated with a major shock – a four-fold oil price rise in 1974 and a financial crisis in 2008 – that caused firms to retrench aggressively. Final demand, however, proved more resilient than expected, resulting in an excessive decline in stock levels that, in turn, prompted a strong production rebound. Fiscal and monetary policies, moreover, were similar: the G7 structural budget deficit widened by 2-3% of GDP in both 1975 and 2009 while official interest rates were cut sharply to below inflation. (This contrasts with the aftermath of the second 1970s oil shock – governments eschewed a Keynesian fiscal response while official rates remained positive in real terms, contributing to a weaker upswing but lower subsequent inflation.) The current revival in G7 plus E7 output, therefore, could continue to track the post-1975 G7 recovery. As the first chart shows, this would imply further solid expansion during 2010, with production surpassing its February 2008 peak at the end of the year, but a significant slowdown in 2011. Indeed, the 2% gain between December 2010 and December 2011 suggested by the template might involve stagnant or contracting G7 industrial activity, allowing for much faster E7 trend growth.
 
This broad shape – strength for much of 2010 but a slowdown in 2011 – appears consistent with global monetary trends. Some monetary economists argue that an economic relapse is imminent because G7 real broad money is now contracting on a year-earlier basis – see the second chart. As discussed in several recent posts, however, negative real interest rates are reducing the demand to hold money by households and financial institutions so this weakness is unlikely to signal insufficient liquidity to finance an ongoing economic recovery. Supporting this interpretation, real narrow money, M1, and corporate broad money holdings – better leading indicators than aggregate broad money – are still growing solidly. M1 expansion, however, has declined since late 2009, consistent with slower economic momentum later this year, in line with the 1970s template.
 
While the economic outlook appears benign, monetary conditions are becoming less favourable for financial markets. The gap between annual G7 real M1 growth and industrial output expansion is a measure of "excess" liquidity available to flow into markets and push up prices. On average since 1970, global equities have outperformed cash by 11% per annum when money has outpaced output while underperforming by 5% pa at other times. The real M1 / output growth gap has been positive since late 2008 but is likely to reverse soon – second chart. Less exciting prospects for equities are also suggested by an analysis of historical recoveries after large bear markets. Prior to the 54% decline between October 2007 and March 2009, the US Dow Jones industrials index had fallen by 45-55% on six occasions since 1900. On average, the Dow recovered by 59% in the first year after these bear markets but by only 7% in the second year. The first-year gain in the current rally (i.e. from the trough on 9 March 2009) was close to the historical average, at 61%.
 
One reason that equities have tended to perform poorly when G7 real M1 growth has fallen beneath output expansion is that such cross-overs have been followed by a rise in short-term interest rates. There have been nine such signals since 1970; in all cases G7 short rates (i.e. a weighted average of national rates) were higher six to 12 months later. Reassured by central bankers' rhetoric about output gaps and the economic drag from future fiscal tightening, markets are currently assuming that monetary policies will remain unusually loose for a sustained period. Such complacency is certainly misplaced in many emerging economies now on the verge of overheating. Even in the G7, likely confirmation that the recovery is spreading to labour markets will allay “double dip” concerns and increase debate about the wisdom of maintaining official rates far below both current and target inflation. The linkage of prolonged periods of negative real rates with the formation of financial bubbles and subsequent damaging busts must surely now be recognised even by the neo-Keynesian dogmatists who populate the major central banks.



PrintView Printer Friendly Version

EmailEmail Article to Friend

Reader Comments

There are no comments for this journal entry. To create a new comment, use the form below.

PostPost a New Comment

Enter your information below to add a new comment.
Author Email (optional):
Author URL (optional):
Post:
 
Some HTML allowed: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <code> <em> <i> <strike> <strong>